News

Economic Forecast: This Year’s Model May Disappoint News
Is this how policymakers will view economists when models don't perform as hoped? (Photo: jeneeze/Flickr/CC BY-NC 2.0)

Economic Forecast: This Year’s Model May Disappoint

February 3, 2017 849

Economic prognosticator

Is this how policymakers will view economists when models don’t perform as hoped? (Photo: jeneeze/Flickr/CC BY-NC 2.0)

It has been a rough 12 months for economists. We have been ignored by voters, ridiculed by politicians and been told that our discipline is in crisis.

At its heart, the so-called “crisis” in economics is simply a result of the flaws in our species. Simply put, the variables used by economists are inherently problematic as they are attempts to model human decision making. What this should tell us is that the value in economics is not in some magical ability to divine the future.

The trouble is, forecasting models are very attractive. They help investors assess risk, help central banks decide policy and allow politicians to justify ideological flights of fancy. And it’s in this last group that the caveats, warnings and limitations of these models are so often ignored.

Being human
Let’s look at those inherent problems in human decision making a little more closely. Let us say that an economy has grown by 3 percent every year for the past 20 years. A forecasting model, based on historical growth will rightly forecast future growth with a high probability of about 3 percent. Does this mean this is guaranteed? Of course not.

The Conversation logo

This article by Richard Whittle originally appeared at The Conversation, a Social Science Space partner site, under the title “How to be an economist in 2017”

The model does not take into account that GDP is a product of human decision making. Just because we have constantly performed one action over and over again, are we destined to in perpetuity? GDP is an observation of our confidence, our tastes, our decisions to spend or save and so much more. These factors are in turn affected by countless others, the isolation of which is impossible due to their constantly changing nature.

I have something at stake in the debate. Right now, I am in the process of devising a model of the UK economy which incorporates relevant psychological drivers of decision making. In my model, I use proxies for people’s confidence and try to build in measures for this confidence to disappear very quickly – for instance how a major news story about people falling into negative equity might dent house buying confidence.

I also try to build in herd-like behavior. And there are a host of other psychological effects to consider too. Did you know that people normally browse a holiday on a mobile phone or tablet but prefer to book it on a home computer? This is the same for most large purchases and the cumulative effects on the economy can be considerable.

It’s those pesky humans again, making everything complicated. You are less likely to impulse buy online if you have to enter your card details. Again this has a noticeable effect on the economy as new financial technology – such as contactless payments – makes unnecessary purchases more likely.

Doctoring the models
Now, this model performs very well in tests designed to assess the robustness of forecasting. It identifies a general slowdown in confidence throughout 2017 culminating in a large downturn in general economic indicators at the end of the year. It seems plausible. However, I show this model to my students as an example of overconfidence in forecasting.

You see, it might produce statistically robust forecasts, but it cannot present the full picture and so its use as a means of prediction is limited. The unknown conditions of Brexit may play a part, the weather may do as well. Without knowing these outcomes, and people’s response to them, my model is incomplete.

So, do I throw up my hands and curse economics as a futile endeavor? Just what is the value of the academic discipline to which I have (so far) devoted my career? Well, the analogy of a medical doctor is useful here.

Designing this model gives a better understanding of the economy even if it can’t guide it down a path of unblemished progress. In the same way, a doctor cannot definitely prevent illness, but can offer advice on prevention and hopefully offer a cure if you do get ill. This is the same for the work economists do.

Economists can offer advice on preventing crises or slowdowns but cannot definitively prevent them from happening. Economists can also offer robust advice on restoring growth, although when the advice is that the economy has grown too fast and should slow, it is often not welcomed by policy makers. This advice is built on a strong evidence base, however just like a doctor prescribing a cure, it is foolhardy to say exactly when the cure will definitely work, or if it will adapt to changing conditions.

Odds on
Perhaps the hard part is getting people to acknowledge these realities. There remains a prevailing view that an economics model makes a definitive forecast for the future – some economists themselves are guilty of maintaining an ideological belief in a method regardless of empirical observation. In fact, economics models simply suggest a version of the future, and incorporate the likelihood of that future occurring.

My model meets a strenuous robustness check, but I still query the use of it as a forecasting tool. I can see, however, why these forecasts are extremely attractive to policy makers.

There is comfort in statistics, and our processing of probabilities is flawed. Someone making a bet with an 80 percent likelihood of success will be disproportionately disappointed if they lose. This is because we tend to overweight such high probabilities as a certainty and already expect the winnings before the outcome, whereas in reality there is a one in five chance of a loss. The opposite is true too. The very small chance of all the factors responsible for an economic crisis converging together at a particular time reassures people that it will never happen.

Policy makers are as susceptible to this as anyone, and should appreciate that the true value of the economist lies not in mystical fortune telling, but in achieving a better understanding of the nature of the economies in which we live and work.The Conversation


Richard Whittle is a research fellow in economics at Manchester Metropolitan University. He began researching at MMU in 2010 and has taught economics at all levels as well as on various professional and industry qualifications,He leads the HMRC Programme in Taxation and Fiscal Policy and is head of the Centre for Applied Behavioural Economics.

View all posts by Richard Whittle

Related Articles

Survey Suggests University Researchers Feel Powerless to Take Climate Change Action
Impact
April 18, 2024

Survey Suggests University Researchers Feel Powerless to Take Climate Change Action

Read Now
Daniel Kahneman, 1934-2024: The Grandfather of Behavioral Economics
News
March 27, 2024

Daniel Kahneman, 1934-2024: The Grandfather of Behavioral Economics

Read Now
2024 Holberg Prize Goes to Political Theorist Achille Mbembe
News
March 14, 2024

2024 Holberg Prize Goes to Political Theorist Achille Mbembe

Read Now
New Feminist Newsletter The Evidence Makes Research on Gender Inequality Widely Accessible
Impact
March 4, 2024

New Feminist Newsletter The Evidence Makes Research on Gender Inequality Widely Accessible

Read Now
Contemporary Politics Focus of March Webinar Series

Contemporary Politics Focus of March Webinar Series

This March, the Sage Politics team launches its first Politics Webinar Week. These webinars are free to access and will be delivered by contemporary politics experts —drawn from Sage’s team of authors and editors— who range from practitioners to instructors.

Read Now
There’s Something In the Air…But Is It a Virus? Part 1

There’s Something In the Air…But Is It a Virus? Part 1

The historic Hippocrates has become an iconic figure in the creation myths of medicine. What can the body of thought attributed to him tell us about modern responses to COVID?

Read Now
The Social Sciences Are Under Attack in Higher Education

The Social Sciences Are Under Attack in Higher Education

The social sciences have been a consistent target for political operatives around the United States in recent years., and recent actions at the state level have opened a new front in the long-running conflict.

Read Now
0 0 votes
Article Rating
Subscribe
Notify of
guest

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.

0 Comments
Inline Feedbacks
View all comments