Impact

Deaton’s Victory for Applied Economics, Statisticians

October 14, 2015 1339

Consume message

A scene from the 1988 movie ‘They Live,’ in which a disguised alien race urges humans to ‘consume,’ ‘conform’ and ‘obey.’

Angus Deaton

Angus Deaton

“In physics, Nobel prizes are awarded for being correct while in economics they are often awarded for being brilliant.” So said former World Bank president Robert Zoellick. Economist Angus Deaton noted the contrast and pondered how interesting it might be to classify economics laureates into Zoellick’s two boxes. Now, Deaton himself has won the Nobel prize for economic sciences. He clearly belongs in both.

Deaton was cited for his “three to four decades” of work on consumption. No-one can work in this field without being deeply influenced by what he has done. Wherever one turns in the analysis of consumption, Deaton has been there, has seen deeply into the issue and shaped the questions being asked.

To me, his work is a model of what applied economics ought to be. No award the Nobel committee has made has pleased me as much, for the recognition it gives both him and the type of work he does.

But statisticians can also rejoice in this award, for Deaton is the type of economist who is thoroughly responsive to data.

Welfare and consumer demand

Deaton’s subject matter, at its broadest, is the welfare of households. Understanding how to measure living standards is the foundation of accurately assessing policy outcomes such as poverty and inequality, and understanding how living standards are determined by economic circumstances is the foundation of designing policies to address those social problems. From an economic perspective, living standards are determined by what households consume. Deaton made his name by looking both at how budgets are spent within periods and how spending is spread over periods in a lifetime by borrowing and saving.

Designing policy to promote welfare requires an understanding of how the goods that people consume depend on their incomes and the prices they face. The best model we have for that starts with the assumption that households make choices to best satisfy their preferences given what they can afford. Such a model not only structures interpretation of behavior but also allows us to infer things about how prices and incomes affect their welfare. Design of taxes on goods, say, can thus be made to best serve households’ interests – a topic of early interest in his career.

But a specification that is too simple may neither fit the data nor leave scope for evidence to decide the policy questions we are interested in. Too complex a specification and we are left with an uninterpretable mess. Deaton, with colleague John Muellbauer, crafted a model – the Almost Ideal Demand System – which strikes a near-ideal balance between these considerations. It has become the mainstay of applied work. Easily estimated, delivering straightforward tests of the underlying theory, but flexible enough to describe data well, the Almost Ideal model is an exemplary marriage of applied work and economic theory.

Beyond this, Deaton’s contributions to demand analysis are legion, always aimed at a sophisticated bridging of the gap between the necessary simplifications of theory and the nuances of applied work. He has helped us understand, for example, how to compare economic well-being between households of different demographic types in a way that is consistent with demand behaviour; or how to incorporate a recognition of how the prices consumers pay for goods may reflect decisions on quality choice.

Consumption and saving
The second strand to Deaton’s work mentioned in the Nobel citation covers the allocation of spending over time. Once, this was a concern more of macroeconomics than microeconomics but Deaton, with his co-authors, has been a pioneer in treating consumption and savings behavior empirically at the household level. This focus on the household is central to his work – assuming lessons about individuals can be learned from aggregates is typically “as dangerous and misleading” as it is “unrealistic.”

Empirical work here is problematic because households’ lives are longer than the periods over which they are observed in surveys. His work develops techniques to overcome this by combining data sources, grouping households by dates of birth and following generations across surveys so that the right questions can be addressed.

From that work emerges an understanding of how households learn and adapt to the arrival of information about lifetime incomes by changing their consumption plans as they age. Different sorts of shocks – sometimes temporary, sometimes permanent – can be accommodated differently and feed through differently into spending as, within each generation, cumulation of shocks drives inequality in consumption and income.

Finally, the application of Deaton’s work to the understanding of poverty in developing countries – especially through the use of household survey data – is credited with “immense practical significance.”

Combining data and theory
Many different themes run through Deaton’s work – one of which is an emphasis on the importance of measurement. In his view, data collection and economic theory have become too separated, to the advantage of neither the data collector nor the economic theorist. Collectors need the guidance of theory and analysts need to understand the data they work with. Too often, Deaton says: “what we think we know about the world is dependent on data that may not mean what we think they mean.”

There is always stress on the integration of measurement and theory, but the sort of theorizing of which Deaton is a master is not idle abstraction but woven into applied analysis. In this he aligns himself with the views of the Irish economist Terence Gorman: “who saw the task of theory as providing models and methods that made life easier for applied analysis.”

Deaton regrets the possibility that “the mold for that kind of theorist has been lost.” Through his own work, however, he shows us that such integration is still possible.The Conversation


Ian Preston is professor in the Department of Economics at University College London. He received his D.Phil in economics from Nuffield College, Oxford in 1989. He is a research fellow of the Institute for Fiscal Studies and is deputy research director of the Centre for Research and Analysis of Migration at UCL. He has been the editor of the Economic Journal Conference Volume and of Fiscal Studies. His main research interests are in applied microeconomics, particularly consumer demand, consumption and savings, income distribution, taxation, public spending and child costs, political economy and the economics of sport. His interests in the economics of migration concern especially the impact on receiving countries and the nature of attitudes towards immigrants.

View all posts by Ian Preston

Related Articles

Three Decades of Rural Health Research and a Bumper Crop of Insights from South Africa
Impact
March 27, 2024

Three Decades of Rural Health Research and a Bumper Crop of Insights from South Africa

Read Now
Using Translational Research as a Model for Long-Term Impact
Impact
March 21, 2024

Using Translational Research as a Model for Long-Term Impact

Read Now
2024 Holberg Prize Goes to Political Theorist Achille Mbembe
News
March 14, 2024

2024 Holberg Prize Goes to Political Theorist Achille Mbembe

Read Now
AAPSS Names Eight as 2024 Fellows
Announcements
March 13, 2024

AAPSS Names Eight as 2024 Fellows

Read Now
Britain’s Academy of Social Sciences Names Spring 2024 Fellows

Britain’s Academy of Social Sciences Names Spring 2024 Fellows

Forty-one leading social scientists have been named to the Spring 2024 cohort of fellows for Britain’s Academy of Social Sciences.

Read Now
Norman B. Anderson, 1955-2024: Pioneering Psychologist and First Director of OBSSR

Norman B. Anderson, 1955-2024: Pioneering Psychologist and First Director of OBSSR

Norman B. Anderson, a clinical psychologist whose work as both a researcher and an administrator saw him serve as the inaugural director of the U.S. National Institute of Health’s Office of Behavioral and Social Sciences Research and as chief executive officer of the American Psychological Association, died on March 1.

Read Now
New Feminist Newsletter The Evidence Makes Research on Gender Inequality Widely Accessible

New Feminist Newsletter The Evidence Makes Research on Gender Inequality Widely Accessible

Gloria Media, with support from Sage, has launched The Evidence, a feminist newsletter that covers what you need to know about gender […]

Read Now
0 0 votes
Article Rating
Subscribe
Notify of
guest

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.

0 Comments
Inline Feedbacks
View all comments