International Debate

Viewing ‘Homo economicus’ Through Prism of Behavioral Economics International Debate
"I'm thinking that with a nudge here and a nudge there we can out-compete those neanderthals." (Image: Henry Gilbert and Kathy Schick/CC BY-SA 3.0)

Viewing ‘Homo economicus’ Through Prism of Behavioral Economics

May 27, 2016 1662

Daka home erectus

“I’m thinking that with a nudge here and a nudge there we can out-compete those neanderthals.” (Image: Henry Gilbert and Kathy Schick/CC BY-SA 3.0)

Once, behavioral economics was a fledgling challenge to traditional theories. Not any longer; it has matured into a growing field that tries to understand how psychology affects economic decisions.

The tension between traditional and behavioral economics is centered on a fundamental issue of human behavior. Economists have long built their discipline around a view of humans as rational actors who know how to maximize their own happiness – the “homo economicus,” or economic man. Supporters of behavioral economics say that, to the contrary, humans are anything but rational. They argue that a keener understanding of human motivations and incentives can sharpen economic models, improve policy decisions in government and business, and have a positive influence on enterprises as discrete as lunch choices, retirement savings or how companies engage with their customers.

LSE Business Review logo

This article by Ken Fireman originally appeared on the LSE Business Review blog as “Behavioural economics challenges traditional view of ‘homo economicus'” and is reposted under the Creative Commons license (CC BY-NC-ND 2.0).

Critics of behavioral economics retort that it has sharply delineated limitations – and that its efforts to influence behavior, sometimes known as nudges, aren’t as powerful as the field’s cheerleaders hope. Some question the propriety of this approach, whether it is government or business that’s doing the nudging. They also doubt proponents’ contentions that behavioral economics can make managers and companies more effective and that it will eventually subsume traditional economics.

Victoria Finkle, a freelance journalist who covers business, banking and public policy, writes in her report “Will a better understanding of behavior improve economic models?” for SAGE Business Researcher that companies and governments have applied the principles of behavioral economics to influence consumers and citizens to modify their behavior. One of the best-known applications is the nudge, an idea popularized by behavioral researchers Richard Thaler and Cass Sunstein, which has had numerous public-policy and private-sector applications.

“A nudge . . . is any aspect of the choice architecture that alters people’s behavior in a predictable way without forbidding any options or significantly changing their economic incentives,” Thaler and Sunstein wrote.  “To count as a mere nudge, the intervention must be easy and cheap to avoid. Nudges are not mandates. Putting the fruit at eye level counts as a nudge. Banning junk food does not.”

This so-called choice architecture is present in every decision people make, whether they’re aware of it or not. “The cafeteria will be organized one way or another – fruit and candy will both be served – so why not do it in a way that will encourage people to make healthy decisions?” Finkle writes.

The field also seeks to draw on insights and techniques from scientific disciplines, such as neuroscience. Johannes Haushofer, a professor of psychology and public affairs at Princeton University, wanted to study how poverty, stress and economic decision-making interacted. In particular, he was interested in the impact of interventions such as unconditional cash transfers to poor people. Instead of asking recipients how they felt about it, he measured their cortisol levels.

“If you ask people how happy they are, they might just tell you they’re pretty happy because they’re grateful for this cash transfer,” he says. “The advantage of measuring stress hormones is you don’t have to worry about that, it’s an objective measure.”

But when does a nudge become a shove? There’s no clear line, Finkle writes. And skeptics of the behavioral approach have pointed out some stark real-world limitations, especially when grappling with society’s most intractable problems. One study found that applying various strategies to encourage poor people to save more didn’t work, for one simple reason: “liquidity constraints,” otherwise known as not having enough money.

Also worrisome is the possibility that behavioural approaches can be applied to enterprises that are more concerned with private gain than public weal. “You can think of it as having a light side and a dark side,” says John Beshears, an assistant professor of business administration at Harvard Business School.

Yet amid the ongoing debate, there is a sense of convergence.

Thaler, for example, wrote in his 2015 book, Misbehaving, that the field of behavioral economics will disappear entirely if all economists “are willing to incorporate important variables in their work, even if the rational model says those variables are supposedly irrelevant.” In such an apotheosis, he wrote, “all economics will be as behavioural as it needs to be.”

David Levine, a professor of economics at Washington University in St. Louis, who has been critical of some behavioral economic insights, reaches a similar conclusion, albeit from the opposite starting point. While he says behavioral economics is “doomed” as a separate field of study, he adds:  “The parts that are good will become part of mainstream economics and people won’t view them as some sort of different discipline or separate subject.”

***
SAGE Publishing is the parent of Social Science Space.


Ken Fireman is managing editor for SAGE Business Researcher. He was previously a senior editor for economics and politics at Bloomberg News and a White House correspondent, national political reporter and Moscow bureau chief for Newsday. He tweets @kfireman1.

View all posts by Ken Fireman

Related Articles

All Change! 2024 – A Year of Elections: Campaign for Social Science Annual Sage Lecture
Event
October 10, 2024

All Change! 2024 – A Year of Elections: Campaign for Social Science Annual Sage Lecture

Read Now
‘Settler Colonialism’ and the Promised Land
International Debate
September 27, 2024

‘Settler Colonialism’ and the Promised Land

Read Now
Webinar: Banned Books Week 2024
Event
September 24, 2024

Webinar: Banned Books Week 2024

Read Now
Research Assessment, Scientometrics, and Qualitative v. Quantitative Measures
Impact
September 23, 2024

Research Assessment, Scientometrics, and Qualitative v. Quantitative Measures

Read Now
Revisiting the ‘Research Parasite’ Debate in the Age of AI

Revisiting the ‘Research Parasite’ Debate in the Age of AI

The large language models, or LLMs, that underlie generative AI tools such as OpenAI’s ChatGPT, have an ethical challenge in how they parasitize freely available data.

Read Now
Trippin’ Forward: Management Research and the Development of Psychedelics

Trippin’ Forward: Management Research and the Development of Psychedelics

Charlie Smith reflects on his interest in psychedelic research, the topic of his research article, “Psychedelics, Psychedelic-Assisted Therapy and Employees’ Wellbeing,” published in Journal of Management Inquiry.

Read Now
Crafting the Best DEI Policies: Include Everyone and Include Evidence

Crafting the Best DEI Policies: Include Everyone and Include Evidence

Organizations shouldn’t back away from workplace DEI efforts. Rather, the research suggests, they should double down, using a more inclusive approach that emphasizes civility and dialogue – one aimed at finding common ground.

Read Now
0 0 votes
Article Rating
Subscribe
Notify of
guest

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.

0 Comments
Newest
Oldest Most Voted
Inline Feedbacks
View all comments